Fateful Lightning: A New History of the Civil War & Reconstruction by Allen Guelzo (self help books to read TXT) π
Read free book Β«Fateful Lightning: A New History of the Civil War & Reconstruction by Allen Guelzo (self help books to read TXT) πΒ» - read online or download for free at americanlibrarybooks.com
- Author: Allen Guelzo
Read book online Β«Fateful Lightning: A New History of the Civil War & Reconstruction by Allen Guelzo (self help books to read TXT) πΒ». Author - Allen Guelzo
Lincoln would need those majorities particularly for handling the needs of war finance and the impact the war would have on the Northern economy. From the first call for volunteers, it was clear that some way had to be found to harness the Northβs unquestioned industrial and financial superiority to the task of winning the war. Lincoln professed to have no expertise in finance. βMoney,β remarked Lincoln, when Treasury Secretary Chase brought a group of New York bankers to the White House to discuss war finance, βI donβt know anything about βmoney.β I never had enough of my own to fret me, and I have no opinion about it any way.β In truth, Lincoln had been interested in fiscal issues as far back as his days in the Illinois legislature, when he had been the point man for the Illinois state bank, and he had been bitterly critical of the Democratsβ national financial policies all through the 1840s. βFinance will rule the country for the next fifty years,β Lincoln predicted to William Pitt Kellogg, and with that in mind, he wanted βthe Capital of the country to become interested in the sustaining of the national credit.β He βhad taken an especial interestβ in Chaseβs financial strategy, and βMr. C. had frequently consulted him in regard to it.β56
It was actually not Lincoln but Chase who lacked experience in βmoney.β Chase was a onetime Democrat who had thrown his allegiance to the Republicans over slavery and Kansas-Nebraska, and he had never fit comfortably with the Whigs or the Whiggish economic views that abounded in the new party. Chase was skeptical on tariffs, hesitant about the virtues of federally financed βinternal improvements,β and so resolutely set against banks that in 1853 he had supported a restructuring of the Treasury to prevent the Treasury from borrowing money (Congress should exercise the sole right to authorize borrowing), setting interest rates on Treasury securities, or using commercial bank accounts for government payables or receivables. He opposed βa mere paper money system of currency,β had railed βagainst the frauds and undue expansions of banks and their suspensions of payment on their issues and deposits,β and had criticized tariffs βin favor of free trade.β57 Now he was in charge of them all.
Of course, part of the rationale for appointing Chase as secretary of the Treasury was precisely that he was a former Democrat and so could assuage the fears of other Democrats for the nationβs fiscal policy. Still, that did nothing to ease the pains of Chaseβs distaste for such responsibilities, or the flimsy structures of government finance that he inherited from his erstwhile Democratic friends. The nationβs financial and banking system was in 1861 still very largely what Andrew Jackson and the Democrats had made it in the 1830s. Suspicious of the market revolution and of finance capitalism, Jackson demolished the federally sponsored Bank of the United States, and the Treasury became little more than a warehouse for government cash and customs receipts. This meant that banking became a matter for individual state governments to charter, which each state did mostly by its own lights. Jackson also took the added precaution of restricting all federal government monetary transactions to specie (which the Democrats regarded as the only real money), so the Treasury would neither accept paper money for itself nor print its own. No such restriction applied to the state-chartered banks, and so by 1861 the American economy was riding on a crazy quilt of banknotes and bonds issued by more than 5,000 state-chartered institutions (including canal companies). No merchant could do business without publications like Dayβs New-York Bank Note List, Counterfeit Detector and Price Current, Bicknellβs Reporter, Counterfeit Detector, and Philadelphia Prices Current, or the Cincinnati Price Current to learn which banknotes were worth the value printed on their faces, which had to be discounted, and which were no longer anything more than paper.58
The great virtue of this system in Democratic eyes was that it kept economic power dispersed and ensured that the national government would remain small and fiscally weak. However, whatever that might have meant as an asset in peacetime politics, it became another matter entirely in war. Northern banks that had acted as the Southβs financial brokers for decades often had nothing more than Southern banknotes and bonds in their vaults as backing for their own accounts and banknotes, and with the secession of the Southern states, Northern bankers suddenly found that they no longer had any guarantee that Southerners would stand by those notes and bonds, or redeem them for specie. Southern bond prices in New York City plummeted like dead pigeons; of the 913 mercantile and banking firms in New York at the beginning of 1861, only 16 were still in business by yearβs end. At the same time, as secession loomed larger and larger on the horizon, confidence in U.S. bonds and notes spiraled downward; by December 1860 the Treasury had to offer interest rates as high as 12 percent to sell its notes, and U.S. 6 percent bonds could only be sold at a steep 11 percent discount.
The unlooked-for blessing in this disaster was that the collapse of Southern bonds and notes wiped out any fiscal leverage the Confederates might have had on the Northern financial markets in 1861, something that was made worse by the Confederate decision to sequester loans owed by Southerners to Northern finance for the duration of the war. Northern businessmen
Comments (0)