The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) π
Description
The Wealth of Nations is economist Adam Smithβs magnum opus and the foundational text of what today we call classical economics. Its publication ushered in a new era of thinking and discussion about how economies function, a sea change away from the older, increasingly-irrelevant mercantilist and physiocratic views of economics towards a new practical application of economics for the birth of the industrial era. Its scope is vast, touching on concepts like free markets, supply and demand, division of labor, war, and public debt. Its fundamental message is that the wealth of a nation is measured not by the gold in the monarchβs treasury, but by its national income, which in turn is produced by labor, land, and capital.
Some ten years in the writing, The Wealth of Nations is the product of almost two decades of notes, study, and discussion. It was released to glowing praise, selling out its first print run in just six months and going through five subsequent editions and countless reprintings in Smithβs lifetime. It began inspiring legislators almost immediately and continued to do so well into the 1800s, and influenced thinkers ranging from Alexander Hamilton to Karl Marx.
Today, it is the second-most-cited book in the social sciences that was published before 1950, and its legacy as a foundational text places it in the stratosphere of civilization-changing books like Principia Mathematica and The Origin of Species.
Read free book Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πΒ» - read online or download for free at americanlibrarybooks.com
- Author: Adam Smith
Read book online Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πΒ». Author - Adam Smith
Below, here through here. β©
Above, here. β©
Below, here. β©
See Denisart, Article Taux des IntΓ©rΓͺts, tom. iii. p. 18. ββ Smith
J. B. Denisart, Collection de dΓ©cisions nouvelles et de notions relatives Γ la jurisprudence actuelle, 7th ed., 1771, s.v. IntΓ©rΓͺt, subdivision Taux des IntΓ©rΓͺts. This does not go so far as the reduction of 1766. The note appears first in ed. 2. ββ Cannan β©
Below, here. β©
Postlethwayt, Dictionary of Commerce, 2nd ed., 1757, vol. i, p. 877, s.v. Funds, says that the amount of British funds held by foreigners has been estimated by some at one-fifth and by others at one-fourth of the whole debt. But Magens, Universal Merchant (ed. Horsley), 1753, p. 13, thought it βmore than probable that foreigners are not concerned in anything like one-fourth.β He had been informed βthat most of the money which the Dutch have here is in Bank, East India and South Sea stocks, and that their interest in them might amount to one-third of the whole.β Fairman, Account of the Public Funds, 7th ed., 1824, p. 229, quotes βan account drawn up in the year 1762, showing how much of the several funds transferable at the Bank of England then stood in the names of foreigners,β which is also in Sinclair, History of the Public Revenue, pt. iii, 1790, p. 366. From this it appears that foreigners held Β£4,627,858 of Bank stock and Β£10,328,537 in the other funds, which did not include South Sea and East India stock. Fairman had reason to believe that the South Sea holding amounted to Β£2,500,000 and the East Indian to more than Β£500,000, which would make in all about Β£18,000,000. In 1806, he says, the total claiming exemption from income tax (foreigners were exempt) was Β£18,500,000, but this did not include Bank stock. β©
Eds. 1β ββ 3 read βlands.β β©
Above, here through here. β©
Below, pp. here through here. β©
Below, here through here, and here. β©
Eds. 1 and 2 read βcheaper.β β©
Ed. 1 reads βfive and forty,β 8 having probably been misread as 5. β©
Ad Atticum, VI, i, 5, 6. Cicero had arranged that a six-year-old debt should be repaid with interest at the rate of 12 percent per annum, the principal being increased by that amount for each of the six years. This would have very nearly doubled the principal, but Brutus, through his agent, kept asking for 48 percent, which would have multiplied it by more than fifteen. However, Cicero asserted that the 12 percent would have satisfied the cruellest usurers. β©
Lectures, pp. 130β ββ 134. β©
I.e., the danger of evading the law. β©
Esprit des lois, liv. xxii, ch. 19, βLβusure augmente dans les pays mahomΓ©tans Γ proportion de la sΓ©vΓ©ritΓ© de la dΓ©fense: le prΓͺteur sβindemnise du pΓ©ril de la contravention. Dans ces pays dβOrient, la plupart des hommes nβont rien dβassurΓ©; il nβy a presque point de rapport entre la possession actuelle dβune somme et lβespΓ©rance de la ravoir aprΓ¨s lβavoir prΓͺtΓ©e: lβusure y augmente donc Γ proportion du pΓ©ril de lβinsolvabilitΓ©.β β©
Joshua Gee, Trade and Navigation of Great Britain Considered, 1729, p. 128, notices the fact of the Dutch being all engaged in trade and ascribes it to the deficiency of valuable land. β©
See below, here through here. β©
According to the view of the subject here set forth, if the three employers each spend Β£100 in wages and materials, and profits are at first 5 percent and then rise to 10 percent, the finished commodity must rise from Β£331 0s. 3d. to Β£364 2s., while if, on the other hand, the wages rise from Β£100 to Β£105, the commodity will only rise to Β£347 11s. 3d. It is assumed either that profits mean profits on turnover and not on capital per annum, or else that the employers each have their capital turned over once a year. But even when one or other of these assumptions is granted, it is clear that the βsimple interestβ may easily be greater than the βcompound.β In the examples just given we doubled profits, but only added one-twentieth to wages. If we double wages and leave profits at 5 percent, the commodity should rise from Β£331 0s. 3d. to Β£662 0s. 6d. β©
This paragraph is not in ed. 1; the epigram at the end, however, did not make its appearance here for the first time in ed. 2, since it occurs in a slightly less polished form here. β©
The general design of this chapter, as well as many of its details, was doubtless suggested by Cantillon, Essai, pt. 1, chaps. vii and viii. The first of these chapters is headed: βLe travail dβun laboureur vaut moins que celui dβun artisan,β and the second: βLes artisans gagnent les uns plus les autres moins selon les cas et les circonstances diffΓ©rentes.β The second ends thus: βPar ces inductions et cent autres quβon pourrait tirer
Comments (0)