American library books Β» Other Β» The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πŸ“•

Read book online Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πŸ“•Β».   Author   -   Adam Smith



1 ... 403 404 405 406 407 408 409 410 411 ... 445
Go to page:
to 63 in January, 1762; rose to 96 in March, 1763; fell again to 80 in October, 1764; after that they were seldom above 90 before the publication of the Wealth of Nations (Sinclair, op. cit., pt. iii, 1790, Appendix iii). The policy of a legal regulation of interest is discussed below, here through here. ↩

Below, here through here. ↩

Above, here. ↩

Below, here. ↩

See Denisart, Article Taux des IntΓ©rΓͺts, tom. iii. p. 18. —⁠Smith

J. B. Denisart, Collection de dΓ©cisions nouvelles et de notions relatives Γ  la jurisprudence actuelle, 7th ed., 1771, s.v. IntΓ©rΓͺt, subdivision Taux des IntΓ©rΓͺts. This does not go so far as the reduction of 1766. The note appears first in ed. 2. —⁠Cannan ↩

Below, here. ↩

Postlethwayt, Dictionary of Commerce, 2nd ed., 1757, vol. i, p. 877, s.v. Funds, says that the amount of British funds held by foreigners has been estimated by some at one-fifth and by others at one-fourth of the whole debt. But Magens, Universal Merchant (ed. Horsley), 1753, p. 13, thought it β€œmore than probable that foreigners are not concerned in anything like one-fourth.” He had been informed β€œthat most of the money which the Dutch have here is in Bank, East India and South Sea stocks, and that their interest in them might amount to one-third of the whole.” Fairman, Account of the Public Funds, 7th ed., 1824, p. 229, quotes β€œan account drawn up in the year 1762, showing how much of the several funds transferable at the Bank of England then stood in the names of foreigners,” which is also in Sinclair, History of the Public Revenue, pt. iii, 1790, p. 366. From this it appears that foreigners held Β£4,627,858 of Bank stock and Β£10,328,537 in the other funds, which did not include South Sea and East India stock. Fairman had reason to believe that the South Sea holding amounted to Β£2,500,000 and the East Indian to more than Β£500,000, which would make in all about Β£18,000,000. In 1806, he says, the total claiming exemption from income tax (foreigners were exempt) was Β£18,500,000, but this did not include Bank stock. ↩

Eds. 1⁠–⁠3 read β€œlands.” ↩

Above, here through here. ↩

Below, pp. here through here. ↩

Below, here through here, and here. ↩

Eds. 1 and 2 read β€œcheaper.” ↩

Ed. 1 reads β€œfive and forty,” 8 having probably been misread as 5. ↩

Ad Atticum, VI, i, 5, 6. Cicero had arranged that a six-year-old debt should be repaid with interest at the rate of 12 percent per annum, the principal being increased by that amount for each of the six years. This would have very nearly doubled the principal, but Brutus, through his agent, kept asking for 48 percent, which would have multiplied it by more than fifteen. However, Cicero asserted that the 12 percent would have satisfied the cruellest usurers. ↩

Lectures, pp. 130⁠–⁠134. ↩

I.e., the danger of evading the law. ↩

Esprit des lois, liv. xxii, ch. 19, β€œL’usure augmente dans les pays mahomΓ©tans Γ  proportion de la sΓ©vΓ©ritΓ© de la dΓ©fense: le prΓͺteur s’indemnise du pΓ©ril de la contravention. Dans ces pays d’Orient, la plupart des hommes n’ont rien d’assurΓ©; il n’y a presque point de rapport entre la possession actuelle d’une somme et l’espΓ©rance de la ravoir aprΓ¨s l’avoir prΓͺtΓ©e: l’usure y augmente donc Γ  proportion du pΓ©ril de l’insolvabilitΓ©.” ↩

Joshua Gee, Trade and Navigation of Great Britain Considered, 1729, p. 128, notices the fact of the Dutch being all engaged in trade and ascribes it to the deficiency of valuable land. ↩

See below, here through here. ↩

According to the view of the subject here set forth, if the three employers each spend Β£100 in wages and materials, and profits are at first 5 percent and then rise to 10 percent, the finished commodity must rise from Β£331 0s. 3d. to Β£364 2s., while if, on the other hand, the wages rise from Β£100 to Β£105, the commodity will only rise to Β£347 11s. 3d. It is assumed either that profits mean profits on turnover and not on capital per annum, or else that the employers each have their capital turned over once a year. But even when one or other of these assumptions is granted, it is clear that the β€œsimple interest” may easily be greater than the β€œcompound.” In the examples just given we doubled profits, but only added one-twentieth to wages. If we double wages and leave profits at 5 percent, the commodity should rise from Β£331 0s. 3d. to Β£662 0s. 6d. ↩

This paragraph is not in ed. 1; the epigram at the end, however, did not make its appearance here for the first time in ed. 2, since it occurs in a slightly less polished form here. ↩

The general design of this chapter, as well as many of its details, was doubtless suggested by Cantillon, Essai, pt. 1, chaps. vii and viii. The first of these chapters is headed: β€œLe travail d’un laboureur vaut moins que celui d’un artisan,” and the second: β€œLes artisans gagnent les uns plus les autres moins selon les cas et les circonstances diffΓ©rentes.” The second ends thus: β€œPar ces inductions et cent autres qu’on pourrait tirer

1 ... 403 404 405 406 407 408 409 410 411 ... 445
Go to page:

Free e-book: Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πŸ“•Β»   -   read online now on website american library books (americanlibrarybooks.com)

Comments (0)

There are no comments yet. You can be the first!
Add a comment