The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) π
Description
The Wealth of Nations is economist Adam Smithβs magnum opus and the foundational text of what today we call classical economics. Its publication ushered in a new era of thinking and discussion about how economies function, a sea change away from the older, increasingly-irrelevant mercantilist and physiocratic views of economics towards a new practical application of economics for the birth of the industrial era. Its scope is vast, touching on concepts like free markets, supply and demand, division of labor, war, and public debt. Its fundamental message is that the wealth of a nation is measured not by the gold in the monarchβs treasury, but by its national income, which in turn is produced by labor, land, and capital.
Some ten years in the writing, The Wealth of Nations is the product of almost two decades of notes, study, and discussion. It was released to glowing praise, selling out its first print run in just six months and going through five subsequent editions and countless reprintings in Smithβs lifetime. It began inspiring legislators almost immediately and continued to do so well into the 1800s, and influenced thinkers ranging from Alexander Hamilton to Karl Marx.
Today, it is the second-most-cited book in the social sciences that was published before 1950, and its legacy as a foundational text places it in the stratosphere of civilization-changing books like Principia Mathematica and The Origin of Species.
Read free book Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πΒ» - read online or download for free at americanlibrarybooks.com
- Author: Adam Smith
Read book online Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πΒ». Author - Adam Smith
Ed. 1 reads βimprovements.β β©
Ed. 1 reads βThough in them.β β©
Another and perhaps more important reason for taking an example like that which follows is the possibility of exhibiting the advantages of division of labour in statistical form. β©
This parenthesis would alone be sufficient to show that those are wrong who believe Smith did not include the separation of employments in βdivision of labour.β β©
In Adam Smithβs Lectures, p. 164, the business is, as here, divided into eighteen operations. This number is doubtless taken from the EncyclopΓ©die, tom. v (published in 1755), s.v. Γpingle. The article is ascribed to M. Delaire, βqui dΓ©crivait la fabrication de lβΓ©pingle dans les ateliers mΓͺme des ouvriers,β p. 807. In some factories the division was carried further. E. Chambers, CyclopΓ¦dia, vol. ii, 2nd ed., 1738, and 4th ed., 1741, s.v. Pin, makes the number of separate operations twenty-five. β©
Ed. 1 reads βthe.β β©
Ed. 1 reads βthe landsβ here and two lines higher up. β©
Ed. 1 reads βbecause the silk manufacture does not suit the climate of England.β β©
In Lectures, p. 164, the comparison is between English and French βtoys,β i.e., small metal articles. β©
Ed. 1 places βin consequence of the division of labourβ here instead of in the line above. β©
βPour la cΓ©lΓ©ritΓ© du travail et la perfection de lβouvrage, elles dΓ©pendent entiΓ¨rement de la multitude des ouvriers rassemblΓ©s. Lorsquβune manufacture est nombreuse, chaque opΓ©ration occupe un homme diffΓ©rent. Tel ouvrier ne fait et ne fera de sa vie quβune seule et unique chose; tel autre une autre chose: dβoΓΉ il arrive que chacune sβexΓ©cute bien et promptement, et que lβouvrage le mieux fait est encore celui quβon a Γ meilleur marchΓ©. Dβailleurs le goΓ»t et la faΓ§on se perfectionnent nΓ©cessairement entre un grand nombre dβouvriers, parce quβil est difficile quβil ne sβen rencontre quelquesuns capables de rΓ©flΓ©chir, de combiner, et de trouver enfin le seul moyen qui puisse les mettre audessus de leurs semblables; le moyen ou dβΓ©pargner la matiΓ¨re, ou dβallonger le temps, ou de surfaire lβindustrie, soit par une machine nouvelle, soit par une maneuver plus commode.β ββ EncyclopΓ©die, tom i (1751), p. 717, s.v. Art. All three advantages mentioned in the text above are included here. β©
In Lectures, p. 166, βa country smith not accustomed to make nails will work very hard for three or four hundred a day and those too very bad.β β©
In Lectures, p. 166, βa boy used to it will easily make two thousand and those incomparably better.β β©
In Lectures, p. 255, it is implied that the labour of making a button was divided among eighty persons. β©
The same example occurs in Lectures, p. 166. β©
Examples are given in Lectures, p. 167: βTwo men and three horses will do more in a day with the plough than twenty men without it. The miller and his servant will do more with the water mill than a dozen with the hand mill, though it too be a machine.β β©
Ed. 1 reads βI shall, therefore, only observe.β β©
Ed. 1 reads βmachines employed.β β©
Ed. 1 reads βof common.β β©
I.e., steam-engines. β©
This pretty story is largely, at any rate, mythical. It appears to have grown out of a misreading (not necessarily by Smith) of the following passage: βThey used before to work with a buoy in the cylinder enclosed in a pipe, which buoy rose when the steam was strong, and opened the injection, and made a stroke; thereby they were capable of only giving six, eight or ten strokes in a minute, till a boy, Humphry Potter, who attended the engine, added (what he called βscogganβ) a catch that the beam Q always opened; and then it would go fifteen or sixteen strokes in a minute. But this being perplexed with catches and strings, Mr. Henry Beighton, in an engine he had built at Newcastle-on-Tyne in 1718, took them all away, the beam itself simply supplying all much better.β ββ J. T. Desaguliers, Course of Experimental Philosophy, vol. ii, 1744, p. 533. From pp. 469, 471, it appears that hand labour was originally used before the βbuoyβ was devised. β©
In Lectures, p. 167, the invention of the plough is conjecturally attributed to a farmer and that of the hand-mill to a slave, while the invention of the waterwheel and the steam engine is credited to philosophers. Mandeville is very much less favourable to the claims of the philosophers: βThey are very seldom the same sort of people, those that invent arts and improvements in them and those that inquire into the reason of things: this latter is most commonly practised by such as are idle and indolent, that are fond of retirement, hate business and take delight in speculation; whereas none succeed oftener in the first than active, stirring and laborious men, such as will put their hand to the plough, try experiments and give all their attention to what they are about.β ββ Fable of the Bees, pt. ii (1729), dial. iii, p. 151. He goes on to give as examples the improvements in soap-boiling, grain-dyeing, etc. β©
The advantage of producing particular commodities wholly or chiefly in the countries most naturally fitted for their production is recognised below, here, but the fact that division of labour is necessary for its attainment is not noticed.
Comments (0)