The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) π
Description
The Wealth of Nations is economist Adam Smithβs magnum opus and the foundational text of what today we call classical economics. Its publication ushered in a new era of thinking and discussion about how economies function, a sea change away from the older, increasingly-irrelevant mercantilist and physiocratic views of economics towards a new practical application of economics for the birth of the industrial era. Its scope is vast, touching on concepts like free markets, supply and demand, division of labor, war, and public debt. Its fundamental message is that the wealth of a nation is measured not by the gold in the monarchβs treasury, but by its national income, which in turn is produced by labor, land, and capital.
Some ten years in the writing, The Wealth of Nations is the product of almost two decades of notes, study, and discussion. It was released to glowing praise, selling out its first print run in just six months and going through five subsequent editions and countless reprintings in Smithβs lifetime. It began inspiring legislators almost immediately and continued to do so well into the 1800s, and influenced thinkers ranging from Alexander Hamilton to Karl Marx.
Today, it is the second-most-cited book in the social sciences that was published before 1950, and its legacy as a foundational text places it in the stratosphere of civilization-changing books like Principia Mathematica and The Origin of Species.
Read free book Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πΒ» - read online or download for free at americanlibrarybooks.com
- Author: Adam Smith
Read book online Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πΒ». Author - Adam Smith
This paragraph appears first in Additions and Corrections and ed. 3. β©
The absence of any reference to the lengthy discussion of this subject in chap. x is curious. β©
Below, here. β©
Ed. 1 reads βthere.β β©
Ed. 1 reads βEqual quantities of labour must at all times and places be.β β©
The words from βIn his ordinary state of healthβ to βdexterityβ appear first in ed. 2. β©
βBe above all things careful how you make any composition or agreement for any long space of years to receive a certain price of money for the corn that is due to you, although for the present it may seem a tempting bargain.β ββ Fleetwood, Chronicon Preciosum, p. 174 β©
Above, here through here. β©
Below, here through here. β©
C. 6, which applies to Oxford, Cambridge, Winchester and Eton, and provides that no college shall make any lease for lives or years of tithes, arable land or pasture without securing that at least one-third of βtholdeβ (presumably the whole not the old) rent should be paid in coin. The Act was promoted by Sir Thomas Smith to the astonishment, it is said, of his fellow-members of Parliament, who could not see what difference it would make. βBut the knight took the advantage of the present cheapness; knowing hereafter grain would grow dearer, mankind daily multiplying, and licence being lately given for transportation. So that at this day much emolument redoundeth to the colleges in each university, by the passing of this Act; and though their rents stand still, their revenues do increase.β ββ Fuller, History of the University of Cambridge, 1655, p. 144, quoted in Strype, Life of the Learned Sir Thomas Smith, 1698, p. 192 β©
Commentaries, 1765, vol. ii, p. 322. β©
Above, here. β©
Below, here through here. β©
Below, here, here, and here. β©
Below, chap. xi, see esp. here. β©
Ed. 1 reads βit.β β©
Ed. 1 places the βfor exampleβ here. β©
βIn England and this part of the world, wheat being the constant and most general food, not altering with the fashion, not growing by chance: but as the farmers sow more or less of it, which they endeavour to proportion, as near as can be guessed to the consumption, abstracting the overplus of the precedent year in their provision for the next; and vice versa, it must needs fall out that it keeps the nearest proportion to its consumption (which is more studied and designed in this than other commodities) of anything, if you take it for seven or twenty years together: though perhaps the scarcity of one year, caused by the accidents of the season, may very much vary it from the immediately precedent or following. Wheat, therefore, in this part of the world (and that grain which is the constant general food of any other country) is the fittest measure to judge of the altered value of things in any long tract of time: and therefore wheat here, rice in Turkey, etc., is the fittest thing to reserve a rent in, which is designed to be constantly the same for all future ages. But money is the best measure of the altered value of things in a few years: because its vent is the same and its quantity alters slowly. But wheat, or any other grain, cannot serve instead of money: because of its bulkiness and too quick change of its quantity.β ββ Locke, Some Considerations of the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and Raising the Value of Money, ed. of 1696, pp. 74, 75 β©
Ed. 1 reads βthan one which sells for an ounce at London to.β β©
Below, chap. xi passim. β©
Pliny, lib. xxxiii c. 3. ββ Smith
This note is not in ed. 1. ββ Cannan β©
Eds. 1 and 2 read βalways.β β©
Habere aes alienum. β©
Ed. 1 does not contain βsterling.β β©
Ed. 1 places the βoriginallyβ here. β©
Ed. 1 places the βonlyβ here. β©
The Act, 19 Hen. VII, c. 5, ordered that certain gold coins should pass for the sums for which they were coined, and 5 and 6 Ed. VI prescribed penalties for giving or taking more than was warranted by proclamation. The value of the guinea was supposed to be fixed by the proclamation of 1717, for which see Economic Journal, March, 1898. Lead tokens were coined by individuals in the reign of Elizabeth. James I coined copper farthing tokens, but abstained from proclaiming them as money of that value. In 1672 copper halfpennies were issued, and both halfpennies and farthings were ordered to pass as money of those values in all payments under sixpence. ββ Harris, Money and Coins, pt. i, Β§ 39; Liverpool, Treatise on the Coins of the Realm, 1805, pp. 130, 131 β©
Ed. 1 reads βsum.β β©
I.e., if 21 pounds may be paid with 420 silver shillings or with 20 gold guineas it does not matter whether a βpoundβ properly signifies 20 silver shillings or Β²β°βββ of a gold guinea. β©
This happens to have been usually, though not always, true, but it is so simply because it has
Comments (0)