The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) π
Description
The Wealth of Nations is economist Adam Smithβs magnum opus and the foundational text of what today we call classical economics. Its publication ushered in a new era of thinking and discussion about how economies function, a sea change away from the older, increasingly-irrelevant mercantilist and physiocratic views of economics towards a new practical application of economics for the birth of the industrial era. Its scope is vast, touching on concepts like free markets, supply and demand, division of labor, war, and public debt. Its fundamental message is that the wealth of a nation is measured not by the gold in the monarchβs treasury, but by its national income, which in turn is produced by labor, land, and capital.
Some ten years in the writing, The Wealth of Nations is the product of almost two decades of notes, study, and discussion. It was released to glowing praise, selling out its first print run in just six months and going through five subsequent editions and countless reprintings in Smithβs lifetime. It began inspiring legislators almost immediately and continued to do so well into the 1800s, and influenced thinkers ranging from Alexander Hamilton to Karl Marx.
Today, it is the second-most-cited book in the social sciences that was published before 1950, and its legacy as a foundational text places it in the stratosphere of civilization-changing books like Principia Mathematica and The Origin of Species.
Read free book Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πΒ» - read online or download for free at americanlibrarybooks.com
- Author: Adam Smith
Read book online Β«The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith (the best motivational books .TXT) πΒ». Author - Adam Smith
Ed. 1 reads βstandardsβ here and seven lines lower. β©
See above here. β©
This erroneous statement has already been made, here; see below, here, for details. β©
Already mentioned above, here. β©
Ed. 2 and later Eds. read erroneously βof the two.β β©
See the preface to the 4th ed., above. β©
Ed. 1 reads βThose deposits of coin, or which.β β©
Eds. 1β ββ 3 have the more correct but awkward reading βthan of those of gold.β β©
The following are the prices at which the bank of Amsterdam at present (September 1775) receives bullion and coin of different kinds:
Silver Mexico dollars Guilders. Bβ β22 per mark French crowns English silver coin Mexico dollars new coin 21 10 Ducatoons 3 Rix dollars 2 8Bar silver containing ΒΉΒΉβββ fine silver 21 per mark, and in this proportion down to ΒΌ fine, on which 5 guilders are given.
Fine bars, 23 per mark.
Gold Portugal coin Bβ β310 per mark Guineas Louis dβors new Ditto old 300 New ducats 4 19 8 per ducatBar or ingot gold is received in proportion to its fineness compared with the above foreign gold coin. Upon fine bars the bank gives 340 per mark. In general, however, something more is given upon coin of a known fineness, than upon gold and silver bars, of which the fineness cannot be ascertained but by a process of melting and assaying. β©
Ed. 1 reads βitβ here. β©
Lectures, pp. 193, 194. The story is doubtless in Voltaire, SiΓ¨cle de Louis XIV, chap. x, and is quoted thence by Anderson, Commerce, AD 1672. β©
N. Magens, Universal Merchant, ed. Horsley, pp. 32, 33, who also protests against the common exaggeration, gives 3,000 as a maximum estimate for the number of accounts, and 60,000,000 guilders as the utmost amount of the treasure. β©
Ed. 1 runs on here as follows, βBut though the computed exchange must generally be in favour of the former, the real exchange may frequently be in favour of the latter.β β©
In place of this part heading (see this note) ed. 1 reads, in square-bracketed italics, βEnd of the Digression concerning Banks of Deposit.β β©
In place of this first line ed. 1 reads, βThough the computed exchange between any two places were in every respect the same with the real, it would not always follow that what is called the balance of trade was in favour of that place which had the ordinary course of exchange in its favour. The ordinary course of exchange might, indeed, in this case, be a tolerable indication of the ordinary state of debt and credit between them, and show which of the two countries usually had occasion to send out money to the other. But the ordinary state of debt and credit between any two places is not always entirely regulated by the ordinary course of their dealings with one another, but is influenced by that of the dealings of both with many other countries. If it was usual, for example, for the merchants of England to pay the goods which they buy from Hamburg, Danzig, Riga, etc., by bills upon Holland, the ordinary state of debt and credit between England and Holland would not be entirely regulated by the ordinary course of the dealings of those two countries with one another, but would be influenced by that of England with those other places. England might, in this case, be annually obliged to send out money to Holland, though its annual exports to that country exceeded the annual value of its imports from it, and though what is called the balance of trade was very much in favour of England.
βHitherto I have been endeavouring to show.β See this note. β©
Below, here through here. β©
Ed. 1 does not contain βand preparing for the market.β β©
Above, here. β©
Eds. 1 and 2 read βmake.β β©
Ed. 1 reads βfrom either.β β©
Lectures, p. 179. β©
Above, here. β©
Below, here. β©
See below, here. β©
See below, here. β©
This and the preceding paragraph appear first in Additions and Corrections and ed. 3. β©
Above, here; Lectures, p. 207. β©
This paragraph was written in the year 1775. ββ Smith
But not exactly as it stands, since ed. 1 reads βthe late disturbancesβ instead of βthe present disturbances.β We can only conjecture that Smith thought that the disturbances were past either when he was writing or when he returned the proof to the printers, or that they would be past by the time his book was published. The alteration of βlateβ to βpresentβ was made in ed. 2, and the footnote added in ed. 3. In vol. ii all Eds. read βpresent disturbancesβ on pp. 75, 86 and 115 and βlate disturbancesβ on p. 79. The two expressions could scarcely have been used at the same time, so we must suppose that βlateβ was corrected into βpresentβ on pp. 75, 86 and 115, or that βpresentβ was corrected into βlateβ on p. 79, but we cannot tell for certain which of the two things happened. ββ Cannan β©
Eds. 1 and 2 read βgo to it.β β©
The next three pages are
Comments (0)